Analytical finance: volume I the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation.
This book is based upon lecture notes, used and developed for the course Analytical Finance I at Mälardalen University in Sweden. The aim is to cover the most essential elements of valuing derivatives on equity markets. This will also include the maths needed to understand the theory behind the...
Saved in:
Main Author: | |
---|---|
Format: | Book |
Language: | English |
Published: |
Palgrave
2020
|
Subjects: | |
Online Access: | http://dspace.uniten.edu.my/jspui/handle/123456789/15356 |
Tags: |
Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
|
id |
my.uniten.dspace-15356 |
---|---|
record_format |
dspace |
institution |
Universiti Tenaga Nasional |
building |
UNITEN Library |
collection |
Institutional Repository |
continent |
Asia |
country |
Malaysia |
content_provider |
Universiti Tenaga Nasional |
content_source |
UNITEN Institutional Repository |
url_provider |
http://dspace.uniten.edu.my/ |
language |
English |
topic |
Mathematic, finance |
spellingShingle |
Mathematic, finance Jan R. M. Röman. Analytical finance: volume I the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation. |
description |
This book is based upon lecture notes, used and developed for the course
Analytical Finance I at Mälardalen University in Sweden. The aim is to cover
the most essential elements of valuing derivatives on equity markets. This
will also include the maths needed to understand the theory behind the
pricing of the market instruments, that is, probability theory and stochastic
processes. We will include pricing with time-discrete models and models in
continuous time.
First, in Chap. 1 and 2 we give a short introduction to trading, risk and
arbitrage-free pricing, which is the platform for the rest of the book. Then a
number of different binomial models are discussed. Binomial models are important,
not only to understand arbitrage and martingales, but also they are widely
used to calculate the price and the Greeks for many types of derivative. Binomial
models are used in trading software to handle and value several kinds of
derivative, especially Bermudan and American type options. We also discuss
how to increase accuracy when using binomial models. We continue with an
introduction to numerical methods to solve partial differential equations (PDEs)
and Monte Carlo simulations.
In Chap. 3, an introduction to probability theory and stochastic integration
is given. Thereafter we are ready to study continuous finance and partial
differential equations, which is used to model many financial derivatives. We
focus on the Black–Scholes equation in particular. In the continuous time
model, there are no solutions to American options, since they can be exercised
during the entire lifetime of the contracts. Therefore we have no well-defined
boundary condition. Since most exchange-traded options with stocks as underlying are of American type, we still need to use descrete models, such as
the binomial model.
We will also discuss a number of generalizations relating to Black–Scholes,
such as stochastic volatility and time-dependent parameters. We also discuss a
number of analytical approximations for American options.
A short introduction to Poisson processes is also given. Then we study
diffusion processes in general, martingale representation and the Girsanov
theorem. Before finishing off with a general guide to pricing via Black–Scholes
we also give an introduction to exotic options such as weather derivatives and
volatility models.
As we will see, many kinds of financial instrument can be valued via a
discounted expected payoff of a contingent claim in the future. We will denote
this expectation E[X(T)] where X(T) is the so-called contingent claim at time
T. This future value must then be discounted with a risk-free interest rate, r, to
give the present value of the claim. If we use continuous compounding we can
write the present value of the contingent claim as
XðtÞ ¼ e rðT tÞE½XðTÞ :
In the equation above, T is the maturity time and t the present time.
Example: If you buy a call option on an underlying (stock) with maturity
T and strike price K, you will have the right, but not the obligation, to buy the
stock at time T, to the price K. If S(t) represents the stock price at time t, the
contingent claim can be expressed as X(T) ¼ max{S(T) – K, 0}. This means
that the present value is given by
XðtÞ ¼ e r ðT tÞE½XðTÞ ¼ e r ðT tÞE½maxfSðTÞ K, 0g :
The max function indicates a price of zero if K S(T). With this condition
you can buy the underlying stock at a lower (same) price on the market, so the
option is worthless.
By solving this expectation value we will see that this can be given
(in continuous time) as the Black–Scholes–Merton formula. But generally
we have a solution as
XðtÞ ¼ Sð0Þ:Q1ðSðTÞ > KÞ e rðT tÞK:Q2ðSðTÞ > KÞ;
where Q1(S(T) > K) and Q2(S(T) > K) make up the risk neutral probability
for the underlying price to reach the strike price K in different “reference
systems”. This can be simplified to the Black–Scholes–Merton formula as XðtÞ ¼ Sð0Þ:Nðd1Þ e rðT tÞK:Nðd2Þ:
Here d1 and d2 are given (derived) variables. N(x) is the standard normal
distribution with mean 0 and variance 1, so N(d2) represent the probability for
the stock to reach the strike price K. The variables d1 and d2 will depend on the
initial stock price, the strike price, interest rate, maturity time and volatility.
The volatility is a measure of how much the stock price may vary in a specific
period in time. Normally we use 252 days, since this is an approximation of
the number of trading days in a year.
Also remark that by buying a call option (i.e., going long in the option
contract), as in the example above, we do not take any risk. The reason is that
we cannot lose more money than what we invested. This is because we have the
right, but not the obligation, to fulfil the contract. The seller, on the other hand,
takes the risk, since he/she has to sell the underlying stock at price K. So if he/she
doesn’t own the underlying stock he/she might have to buy the stock at a very
high price and then sell it at a much lower price, the option strike price K.
Therefore, a seller of a call option, who have the obligation to sell the underlying
stock to the holder, takes a risky position if the stock price becomes higher than
the option strike price. |
format |
Book |
author |
Jan R. M. Röman. |
author_facet |
Jan R. M. Röman. |
author_sort |
Jan R. M. Röman. |
title |
Analytical finance: volume I the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation. |
title_short |
Analytical finance: volume I the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation. |
title_full |
Analytical finance: volume I the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation. |
title_fullStr |
Analytical finance: volume I the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation. |
title_full_unstemmed |
Analytical finance: volume I the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation. |
title_sort |
analytical finance: volume i the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation. |
publisher |
Palgrave |
publishDate |
2020 |
url |
http://dspace.uniten.edu.my/jspui/handle/123456789/15356 |
_version_ |
1680859867410071552 |
spelling |
my.uniten.dspace-153562020-09-10T03:36:49Z Analytical finance: volume I the mathematics of equity derivatives, markets, risk and valuation. Jan R. M. Röman. Mathematic, finance This book is based upon lecture notes, used and developed for the course Analytical Finance I at Mälardalen University in Sweden. The aim is to cover the most essential elements of valuing derivatives on equity markets. This will also include the maths needed to understand the theory behind the pricing of the market instruments, that is, probability theory and stochastic processes. We will include pricing with time-discrete models and models in continuous time. First, in Chap. 1 and 2 we give a short introduction to trading, risk and arbitrage-free pricing, which is the platform for the rest of the book. Then a number of different binomial models are discussed. Binomial models are important, not only to understand arbitrage and martingales, but also they are widely used to calculate the price and the Greeks for many types of derivative. Binomial models are used in trading software to handle and value several kinds of derivative, especially Bermudan and American type options. We also discuss how to increase accuracy when using binomial models. We continue with an introduction to numerical methods to solve partial differential equations (PDEs) and Monte Carlo simulations. In Chap. 3, an introduction to probability theory and stochastic integration is given. Thereafter we are ready to study continuous finance and partial differential equations, which is used to model many financial derivatives. We focus on the Black–Scholes equation in particular. In the continuous time model, there are no solutions to American options, since they can be exercised during the entire lifetime of the contracts. Therefore we have no well-defined boundary condition. Since most exchange-traded options with stocks as underlying are of American type, we still need to use descrete models, such as the binomial model. We will also discuss a number of generalizations relating to Black–Scholes, such as stochastic volatility and time-dependent parameters. We also discuss a number of analytical approximations for American options. A short introduction to Poisson processes is also given. Then we study diffusion processes in general, martingale representation and the Girsanov theorem. Before finishing off with a general guide to pricing via Black–Scholes we also give an introduction to exotic options such as weather derivatives and volatility models. As we will see, many kinds of financial instrument can be valued via a discounted expected payoff of a contingent claim in the future. We will denote this expectation E[X(T)] where X(T) is the so-called contingent claim at time T. This future value must then be discounted with a risk-free interest rate, r, to give the present value of the claim. If we use continuous compounding we can write the present value of the contingent claim as XðtÞ ¼ e rðT tÞE½XðTÞ : In the equation above, T is the maturity time and t the present time. Example: If you buy a call option on an underlying (stock) with maturity T and strike price K, you will have the right, but not the obligation, to buy the stock at time T, to the price K. If S(t) represents the stock price at time t, the contingent claim can be expressed as X(T) ¼ max{S(T) – K, 0}. This means that the present value is given by XðtÞ ¼ e r ðT tÞE½XðTÞ ¼ e r ðT tÞE½maxfSðTÞ K, 0g : The max function indicates a price of zero if K S(T). With this condition you can buy the underlying stock at a lower (same) price on the market, so the option is worthless. By solving this expectation value we will see that this can be given (in continuous time) as the Black–Scholes–Merton formula. But generally we have a solution as XðtÞ ¼ Sð0Þ:Q1ðSðTÞ > KÞ e rðT tÞK:Q2ðSðTÞ > KÞ; where Q1(S(T) > K) and Q2(S(T) > K) make up the risk neutral probability for the underlying price to reach the strike price K in different “reference systems”. This can be simplified to the Black–Scholes–Merton formula as XðtÞ ¼ Sð0Þ:Nðd1Þ e rðT tÞK:Nðd2Þ: Here d1 and d2 are given (derived) variables. N(x) is the standard normal distribution with mean 0 and variance 1, so N(d2) represent the probability for the stock to reach the strike price K. The variables d1 and d2 will depend on the initial stock price, the strike price, interest rate, maturity time and volatility. The volatility is a measure of how much the stock price may vary in a specific period in time. Normally we use 252 days, since this is an approximation of the number of trading days in a year. Also remark that by buying a call option (i.e., going long in the option contract), as in the example above, we do not take any risk. The reason is that we cannot lose more money than what we invested. This is because we have the right, but not the obligation, to fulfil the contract. The seller, on the other hand, takes the risk, since he/she has to sell the underlying stock at price K. So if he/she doesn’t own the underlying stock he/she might have to buy the stock at a very high price and then sell it at a much lower price, the option strike price K. Therefore, a seller of a call option, who have the obligation to sell the underlying stock to the holder, takes a risky position if the stock price becomes higher than the option strike price. 2020-09-10T03:36:49Z 2020-09-10T03:36:49Z 2017 Book http://dspace.uniten.edu.my/jspui/handle/123456789/15356 en Palgrave |
score |
13.211869 |